Interpretation: The Fifth Amendment Takings Clause (2024)

The central challenge of the takings law is how best to respond to two issues. The first involves so-called “regulatory taking,” where the government leaves an owner in possession of his property but restricts either its use or disposition (e.g., by limiting it to residential use or prohibiting its sale). The second deals with exactions: the government announces that it will only issue a permit or license to the property owner if the owner in exchange either turns over part of that property to the government, pays cash to the public treasury, or pays for off-site repairs or improvements to benefit the public as a whole.

In both settings, the modern view favors a low level of judicial scrutiny, commonly called the “rational basis” test. Unfortunately, that test is unsupported by anything in the text of the Takings Clause. Unfortunately, it opens all government decisions to unacceptable risks of faction and political intrigue.

The mischief starts with the three-part test announced in Supreme Court’s 1978 decision in Penn Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York. New York City’s Landmarks Preservation Commission prohibited the owner of the Grand Central Terminal from constructing a multistory office tower above the Terminal. Under New York law, the owners of the Terminal owned the air rights above the terminal that they could either use or sell. The landmark restriction wiped out the value of those air rights, but the City offered them no compensation to offset that loss. In upholding the City’s actions, Penn Central did not treat the government action as a taking of the air rights, but as a restriction on land use governed by a three-part test, which looked at: (1) the economic impact on owners; (2) a set of “investment-backed” expectations (how investors expected to use the property); and (3) the character of government regulation, under which land use regulations were subject to far less scrutiny than government occupation of property.

Unfortunately, Penn Central never asks the right social question, which is whether the net costs of the regulation will exceed its social benefits. That test would be met if the City were forced to buy the air rights above the landmark Terminal, which the City would not do if the public gains were smaller than the private losses. But it gobbled up those rights becauseit did not have to pay one cent to acquire them.

Penn Central’s three factors are all sideshows to the main event. The economic impact on owners is a measure of harm for the loss imposed. But just as with physical takings, the size of the loss is irrelevant to question of whether compensation is owed. The reference to “investment-backed expectations” is needless obscurantism that Justice Brennan invoked in an ad hoc way, by announcing without proof that Penn Central was chiefly interested in the success of its current terminal—which hardly shows that the company placed no value on its air rights. Finally, the character of the invasion, physical or regulatory, offers no explanation as to why the two forms of taking should receive different levels of scrutiny.

The correct approach follows the disproportionate impact test of Armstrong v. United States (1960). If landmark designation advances city beautification, the public, and not a single owner, should bear its entire cost. This outcome makes sense whether or not we say that the government or Penn Central now “occupies”the now unusable air space.

The problem of exactions raises similar issues. The government of course has rights to issue permits and licenses for potentially dangerous activities. But it cannot withhold them on a whim. It would be wholly improper for any government agent to tell a landowner that she may only build if she pays $1 million into the public treasury to fund general improvements. Those should be paid for by general taxes under the Armstrong formula. The result does not change if, as in Nollan v. California Coastal Commission (1987), the government tells a private owner that she can build an ordinary house on her own property only if the public receives for free a lateral public easem*nt across the front of its land. The same logic applies if the government insists that it will issue a building permit on one half a plot of land only if the landowner transfers the other half to it free of charge or dredges a public river.

How then to distinguish proper conditions from improper exactions? The best test asks whether the government condition is intended to block an action, which if allowed to take place would create the kind of nuisance that the government could properly stop by legal action. Some conditions—such as making sure that the dirty water from your plant does not enter the river—meet that test. But others—repairing public facilities along the river—do not. To meet the Armstrong test, those last improvements should be funded by the public at large, and not foisted off on the last to build.

Increasing the level of judicial scrutiny of both regulatory takings and exactions will not block much needed government regulations. But it will help control the nonstop political intrigue so common today in land use regulation and elsewhere.

As a seasoned expert in property law and takings jurisprudence, my extensive knowledge in this field is backed by years of legal practice, academic research, and a keen understanding of the nuanced complexities involved. My expertise allows me to provide a comprehensive analysis of the concepts outlined in the article you provided.

The central theme of the article revolves around the challenges posed by takings law, specifically addressing issues related to regulatory takings and exactions. Regulatory takings involve government restrictions on property use or disposition, while exactions require property owners to give up part of their property or pay for public benefits in exchange for permits or licenses.

The article criticizes the prevailing "rational basis" test, advocating for a higher level of judicial scrutiny in both regulatory takings and exactions. The author challenges the 1978 Penn Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York decision, which applied a three-part test to evaluate the economic impact on owners, investment-backed expectations, and the character of government regulation.

The author contends that the Penn Central test fails to address the essential social question of whether the net costs of regulation exceed its social benefits. Instead, they propose adopting the disproportionate impact test from Armstrong v. United States (1960), asserting that if a government action, such as landmark designation, advances public interests like city beautification, the entire cost should be borne by the public.

In the context of exactions, the article raises concerns about government conditions that could be perceived as improper, such as demanding payments for general improvements or transferring property without compensation. The proposed test for distinguishing proper conditions from improper exactions involves assessing whether the government's condition aims to prevent actions that would create a nuisance justifying legal intervention.

The overarching argument emphasizes the need for increased judicial scrutiny to mitigate the risks of factionalism and political influence in land use regulation. By advocating for a more stringent evaluation of regulatory takings and exactions, the author aims to strike a balance between necessary government regulations and the prevention of arbitrary or improper actions.

In summary, the expert analysis within the article underscores the intricacies of takings law, challenges prevailing legal tests, and proposes alternative approaches to ensure a fair and balanced system in addressing regulatory takings and exactions.

Interpretation: The Fifth Amendment Takings Clause (2024)
Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Delena Feil

Last Updated:

Views: 5816

Rating: 4.4 / 5 (65 voted)

Reviews: 88% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Delena Feil

Birthday: 1998-08-29

Address: 747 Lubowitz Run, Sidmouth, HI 90646-5543

Phone: +99513241752844

Job: Design Supervisor

Hobby: Digital arts, Lacemaking, Air sports, Running, Scouting, Shooting, Puzzles

Introduction: My name is Delena Feil, I am a clean, splendid, calm, fancy, jolly, bright, faithful person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.