The Lock-in Effect of California's Proposition 13 (2024)

The effect of Proposition 13 on mobility varies widely depending on the size of the subsidy, with the largest effects occurring in coastal California cities where the increase in property values has been greatest.

Proposition 13, adopted by California voters in 1978, mandates a property tax rate of one percent, requires that properties be assessed at market value at the time of sale, and allows assessments to rise by no more than 2 percent per year until the next sale. This means that as long as property values increase by more than 2 percent per year, homeowners gain from remaining in the same house because their taxes are lower than they would be on a different house of the same value. Proposition 13 thus gives rise to a lock-in effect for owner-occupiers that strengthens over time. It also affects the rental market, both directly because it applies to landlords and indirectly because it reduces the turnover of owner-occupied homes.

As a result of Proposition 13, there are obvious distortions in the real estate marketplace. For example, in 2003 financier Warren Buffett announced that he pays property taxes of $14,410, or 2.9 percent, on his $500,000 home in Omaha, Nebraska, but pays only $2,264, or 0.056 percent, on his $4 million home in California. Although Buffet is known as an astute investor, the low property taxes on his California home are not attributable to his investment prowess, but rather to Proposition 13.

In 1992, the U.S. Supreme Court upheld Proposition 13, in part on the grounds that it furthered the policy goals of increasing "...local neighborhood preservation, continuity, and stability." In Property Tax Limitations and Mobility: The Lock-in Effect of California's Proposition 13 (NBER Working Paper No. 11108), authors Nada Wasi and Michelle J. White examine how Proposition 13 has affected the average tenure of owners and renters in California versus other states. They find that Proposition 13 definitely furthered continuity and stability, because it caused a substantial increase in the average tenure of California households relative to that of households in other states. From 1970 to 2000, the average tenure of California homeowners and renters increased by 1.04 and .79 years relative to that of homeowners and renters in the control states. These figures represent increases in average tenure of 10 percent and 19 percent, respectively.

The large effect of Proposition 13 on renters' tenure is particularly striking and suggests that longer tenure by owner-occupiers forces younger households to delay their transition from renting to owning. The authors also find that African-American households responded more strongly to Proposition 13 than white households and out-of-state migrant households responded more strongly than native-born households. From 1970 to 1990, the tenure length of African-American homeowners and renters increased by 1.3 years and 1.8 years, respectively, relative to that of white homeowners and renters. From 1970 to 2000, the tenure length of migrant homeowners and renters increased by 1.5 years and .6 years, respectively, relative to that of native-born homeowners and renters.

The effect of Proposition 13 on mobility varies widely depending on the size of the subsidy, with the largest effects occurring in coastal California cities where the increase in property values has been greatest. From 1970 to 2000, average tenure length increased by less than one year in inland California cities, but by more than two years in the Los Angeles area and by three years in the Bay area. As the authors suggest, whether the Proposition 13- induced increases in continuity and stability have been worth the cost in lost tax revenue and the resulting redistribution from inland to coastal California communities remain subjects for further research

-- Les Picker

Proposition 13 is a landmark piece of legislation in California that significantly impacted property taxation and, consequently, real estate dynamics. This proposition, enacted in 1978, imposed a property tax rate of one percent, assessed properties at market value upon sale, and limited annual assessment increases to a maximum of 2 percent until the property was sold again. I've closely studied Proposition 13's multifaceted effects, particularly its implications for homeowners, renters, the real estate market, and its socio-economic ramifications.

This policy created a lock-in effect for homeowners, incentivizing them to stay in their current residences due to the tax benefits they accrued over time. Consequently, it led to increased stability and continuity in neighborhoods but also resulted in distortions within the real estate market, impacting both rental and ownership sectors. The reduced turnover of owner-occupied homes directly affected rental markets, causing disruptions and influencing the decisions of potential homeowners.

An interesting consequence was the disparity in property taxes for individuals like Warren Buffett, who paid significantly lower taxes on higher-valued properties in California due to Proposition 13. This illustrates how the legislation impacted taxation and contributed to a divergence in tax burdens among property owners across different regions.

Studies, such as the one by Nada Wasi and Michelle J. White, have delved into the effects of Proposition 13 on tenure lengths for homeowners and renters. They observed substantial increases in the average tenure of California households compared to control states. This prolonged tenure had notable demographic implications, impacting African-American households more significantly than white households and affecting migration patterns as well, with out-of-state migrants experiencing longer tenure relative to native-born households.

Moreover, the geographical variation in the effect of Proposition 13 on mobility is crucial. Its impact was more pronounced in coastal California cities with substantial property value increases compared to inland areas, leading to varying degrees of tenure lengthening. For instance, the Los Angeles and Bay areas experienced greater increases in tenure length compared to inland cities, shedding light on the localized impact of this legislation.

The article by Les Picker rightly points out the need for further research to evaluate whether the benefits of increased continuity and stability outweigh the costs in terms of lost tax revenue and potential redistribution effects between different Californian communities.

In summary, Proposition 13 fundamentally reshaped property taxation and had extensive repercussions on tenure lengths, neighborhood stability, rental markets, demographic patterns, and regional disparities across California's real estate landscape.

The Lock-in Effect of California's Proposition 13 (2024)
Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Chrissy Homenick

Last Updated:

Views: 5533

Rating: 4.3 / 5 (54 voted)

Reviews: 85% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Chrissy Homenick

Birthday: 2001-10-22

Address: 611 Kuhn Oval, Feltonbury, NY 02783-3818

Phone: +96619177651654

Job: Mining Representative

Hobby: amateur radio, Sculling, Knife making, Gardening, Watching movies, Gunsmithing, Video gaming

Introduction: My name is Chrissy Homenick, I am a tender, funny, determined, tender, glorious, fancy, enthusiastic person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.