Economics as a Hard Science | Karl Borden, Jacob R Borden (2024)

Economics — the application of scarce resources to productive ends — is generally considered a “social” science. Such classification leads many to presume that the “laws” of economics are social conventions and therefore mutable. But is economics entirely a soft science?

It’s certainly true of some branches of the discipline, such as behavioral economics. A lot of the macroeconomics that goes into setting modern fiscal and monetary policy is contrived by humans and therefore subject to the vagaries of human behavior.

But at a more fundamental level, the laws of economics rest on a foundation that underlies and defines elemental structures inherent in our universe. At that level, economics becomes a “hard” science. Its laws and principles take on the immutability of the laws derived from the observations of natural science.

Understanding the difference between those laws of economics that are “hardwired” into our universe and those that derive from human behavior is fundamental to effective social policy. The latter may be subject to legislative manipulation; the former are not. Too often, policymakers who do not understand the difference try in vain to alter the nature of our universe. And then they wonder why their policies don’t have the intended effect.

Material order

At a fundamental level, all the natural resources at our disposal have this in common: they represent material order — that is, specific arrangements of atoms and molecules. When we speak of the “scarcity” of factors of production, what is fundamentally scarce is the quantity, type, and distribution of material order around the globe and in the universe writ large.

Material order is the phenomenon termed entropy enshrined in the second law of thermodynamics, which prescribes the interaction of energy with matter to effect the dissipation of the universe. Economic scarcity is a manifestation of the second law’s observation that the amount of material disorder in the universe is continuously increasing.

If standard cosmology is true, it all started with the big bang, which saw the entire universe usher forth from a singularity. Just prior to the big bang, that singularity embodied a universe with exactly zero entropy, because in that moment, the universe was also perfectly ordered. With the big bang, a concentrated stream of energy rushed forth, forcing the expansion of space and the progression of time. The universe was no longer ordered perfectly within a single point of infinite smallness. The entropy of the universe had increased. That, in a nutshell, is the second law of thermodynamics: the total entropy of the universe is constantly increasing due to the natural dissipation of universal order, a dissipation that so far appears to be unceasing.

The math describing the second law quantifies entropy as an inverse measure of order, such that something with low entropy is more highly organized. Pure water has less entropy than contaminated water because it is pure. There is a greater degree of order in the uniform arrangement of pure water molecules that is perturbed by the introduction of even a single molecule of contaminant. As dirty water is purified, its order increases and its entropy decreases.

Water, however, does not purify itself in isolation from the rest of the universe. Rather, a universal thermodynamic “price” must be paid to reverse “localized” entropy and create order.

Wealth and the thermodynamic transaction cost

Fast forward from the big bang several billion years, until right around the time certain organizations of particles in a remote arm of the universe became sentient (read: our ancestors). Compared with the zero-entropy singularity, the universe had become decidedly more disordered. Still, until that point, the propagation of energy and matter through the still-expanding universe was unaltered by the concerted action of any particular organization of conscious particles. With human consciousness, however, our organized particles (brains) discovered meaningful ways to affect both the direction and magnitude by which the universe’s entropy would continue to increase. We did this quite selfishly, to improve the order inherent in our own particles. We did it not only to forestall death, but to improve life. We started to become wealthy.

Human activity is all about affecting the magnitude and direction of the universe’s entropy budget — creating localized disorder or order that improves our well-being. In this sense, wealth represents our ability to manipulate material order in ways that enhance human well-being. Even self-organizing systems still operate within the constraints of universal entropic processes. In the material world, think of crystal formation; in the social world, think of Hayekian or Bejanian processes that lead us to ever-more-optimal applications of energy to the localized reversal of entropy that we term “wealth.” Both must still obey the constraints of the second law.

Consider, for instance, early man’s discovery of fire. As it burns, densely packed and highly organized molecules in wood are expelled as chaotic and highly disorganized gases. In the process, we feel heat, a form of energy. The thermodynamic phenomenon we have termed “heat” is simply the result of material order giving way to disorder, which makes heat the means by which the entropy of the universe increases. Early man used fire to generate heat, preserving and improving the human condition, and in the process began accelerating the rate at which universal entropy was increasing.

On the other hand, most modern economic activity is about the localized reversal of entropy. Consider, for instance, a modern loom. The loom more perfectly organizes the atoms and molecules in fibrous strands to produce woven fabric, useful for all sorts of products that increase human welfare. To create this local order, we harvest and combine resources — but we don’t get the increase in order for free. The total entropy of the universe must constantly increase. So we expend energy and expel heat to produce the materials that get ordered into a functional machine, which expends more heat to weave the threads into a fabric.

The key word is total. For any act, we can break this total into two parts: Stotal = Sact + Srest of the universe. By acting economically, we accumulate order and so Sact is less than zero. But, total entropy has to be greater than zero. So Srest of the universe has to be a number greater in absolute value than Sact is negative. Heat is the means by which Srest of the universe is a positive value.

And that is the key point. The expense of heat is the thermodynamic transaction cost exacted in order to accumulate material order, or wealth. Every product of man is the result of using heat to affect the overall rate at which universal entropy and therefore disorder is increasing, so that we may accumulate some lesser amount of desirable material order for our localized benefit.

Entropy and effective economic policy

The overarching implication of a thermoeconomic approach to wealth creation is that, at the level of society and social policy, the unguided evolution of norms and self-organizing institutions represents incremental societal movement in the direction of reaping maximum localized order (wealth) from minimized energy expense and disorder creation. Social orders may spontaneously evolve in the direction of improved ability to produce localized material order with minimum increases in entropy and energy expenditure. But as long as we are living in an expanding universe, the increasing well-being of humans that results from the material order that we term “wealth” must come with an entropic price tag.

For instance, in thermoeconomic terms, resource efficiency is an indication of the amount of local order accumulated relative to the heat expended for the effort. Market equilibria therefore represent the application of dispersed data to resource-allocation decisions that minimize our total entropic footprint during the pursuit of human well-being. Policies or systems that suboptimally allocate resources invariably achieve lower local order for higher levels of heat (energy) expenditure. Energy markets in particular need proper signaling mechanisms to indicate the relative abundance of useful order. Mandates and subsidies for particular types of energy corrupt these mechanisms, lowering efficiency by drawing material order away from those uses inherent in the state of minimum-entropy economic equilibrium.

Another thermoeconomic implication of entropy is that the greater the amount of localized order created (that is, the greater the quantity of goods and services produced), the greater the amount of energy needed to maintain that order against natural entropy. Bananas spoil. Wood rots. Our most durable edifices eventually crumble. When our politicians create order by dedicating available resources to build a road, they also obligate future expenditures of energy to maintain it.

Likewise, thermoeconomics limits our ability to store wealth for future consumption, as every store of wealth eventually dissipates. In that sense, all savings are ephemeral and all consumption is relatively immediate. Financial wealth merely represents a derivative claim on real wealth and the ability to exercise time preferences in our consumption. Whenever we promise the ability to consume in the future, whether the promise is made “to ourselves” (Social Security and other pension plans) or to future generations (529 college savings plans for our grandchildren), we are in fact promising some future expenditure of energy to create future order. The order we have today will be gone by then.

Or consider the eventual need to harvest material order from sources beyond our own terrestrial sphere. Without creating policies that will incentivize our species to identify nongeologic resources, we must eventually reach an equilibrium point between the cost of maintaining our existing order and the thermodynamic “revenue” that we can harvest from the sun, or from the accumulated store of capital embedded in the earth.

The Promethean fire

Modern economic activity is more complex than the fires burned by primitive man, but that activity still hinges on the thermodynamic fundamentals of heat and entropy. Economics at the foundational level of scarcity is hardwired into the universe through the second law, which requires that order accumulated during the pursuit of happiness must be offset by the generation of some greater quantity of disorder. There is, after all, no such thing as a free lunch.

Economics as a Hard Science | Karl Borden, Jacob R Borden (2024)

FAQs

What is the meaning of economics as a science? ›

Economics is the study of scarcity and its implications for the use of resources, production of goods and services, growth of production and welfare over time, and a great variety of other complex issues of vital concern to society.

Who suggested that economics is a social science? ›

Scitovsky said "Economics is a social science concerned with the administration of scarce resources". Just like Robbins, Scitovsky also believed that economics is a science which deals with the study of human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses.

What is the economic theory of science? ›

The economics of science aims to understand the impact of science on the advance of technology, to explain the behavior of scientists, and to understand the efficiency or inefficiency of scientific institutions and science markets.

Is economics the science of choice True or false? ›

Ultimately, economics is the study of choice. Because choices range over every imaginable aspect of human experience, so does economics. Economists have investigated the nature of family life, the arts, education, crime, sports, law—the list is virtually endless because so much of our lives involves making choices.

Who said economics is a science? ›

Lionel Robbins was a British economist and prominent member of the Department of Economics at the London School of Economics. He defined economics as a science that studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means that have alternative uses.

What are three reasons why economics is considered a science? ›

Economics as a science: Like science, economics is also based on the systematic knowledge which is based on facts and data. Like any other science, it has its own scientific laws and theories which can be measured and verified and proved. Also, it has its own methodology.

Who is the father of economics? ›

Adam Smith is the father of Economics.

Why economics is called a science or a social science? ›

Economics is considered a social science because, at its core, economics is the study of human behavior, both the causes and effects. Economics is considered a social science, not a natural science.

Who turned economics into a modern science? ›

To put it simply, Paul Samuelson helped economics become a science.

Who is the most famous economist? ›

Adam Smith (1723–1790)

Educated at the University of Glasgow at the age of 14, he went on to pioneer political economy and is now deemed the 'Father of Modern Economics'. Best known for his book The Wealth of Nations, Smith argued for free trade, market competition and the morality of private enterprise.

What are the 3 major theories of economics? ›

The 3 major theories of economics are Keynesian economics, Neoclassical economics, and Marxian economics. Some of the other theories of economics are monetarism, institutional economics, constitutional economics etc.

What is a real life example of economics? ›

Example #1 – Supply and demand

This example of Economics is the most basic concept of free-market economics that helps determine the right price for a good or service. E.g. a start-up company desires to introduce a fresh product into the market and wants to find the right price for its creation. The product costs.

Is economics a science or a theory? ›

Economics is generally regarded as a social science, which revolves around relationships between individuals and societies.

What is the basic problem of economics? ›

The fundamental problem in economics is the issue with the scarcity of resources but unlimited wants. Economics has also pointed out that a man's needs cannot be fulfilled. The more our needs are fulfilled, the more wants we develop with time. By definition, scarcity implies a limited quantity of resources.

Is economics a science justify your answer? ›

Economics is a science because it deals with understanding the flow of information. Economics deals with the flow of commodified information. Knowledge is information that humans have extracted and is known to them.

What are the features of economics as a science? ›

Economics as a Science

It is quantifiable and uses a proven apparatus to predict the desired results. It is based on experimentation. Economics has all these qualities; it establishes a strong cause and effect relationship for the consumption of goods and services between demand and supply.

How is economics a science quizlet? ›

Economics is a science that studies the choices of economic units regarding the use of scarce resources and the social effects of these choices. Economists study to address their studies with a scientists' objectivity.

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Twana Towne Ret

Last Updated:

Views: 5818

Rating: 4.3 / 5 (64 voted)

Reviews: 95% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Twana Towne Ret

Birthday: 1994-03-19

Address: Apt. 990 97439 Corwin Motorway, Port Eliseoburgh, NM 99144-2618

Phone: +5958753152963

Job: National Specialist

Hobby: Kayaking, Photography, Skydiving, Embroidery, Leather crafting, Orienteering, Cooking

Introduction: My name is Twana Towne Ret, I am a famous, talented, joyous, perfect, powerful, inquisitive, lovely person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.