Balancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (2024)

1Introduction

Central banks hold considerable power in their countries’ economies. While their mandates vary, they generally aim to create the conditions for economic and financial stability. Their most important tools are monetary policies, which are decisions about the value of money. These include decisions about the amount of money in the economy and ways to keep inflationstable.

Most central banks hold some or all of the following powers: setting interest rates, issuing currency, regulating foreign exchange rates, regulating private banks, and acting as a lender (especially an emergency lender) for governments and/or privatebanks.

In light of the considerable power of central banks, lawmakers and central bankers must decide how to balance the banks’ independence from political influence and their accountability to citizens. The result requires trade‑offs between competing principles. On the one hand, central banks need independence, since the best policy for the economy may not align with political goals. On the other hand, in fulfilling their mandate, central banks must be accountable to citizens through theirlawmakers.

There is no single, best compromise between these principles. While every country aims for the “correct” balance between its central bank’s independence and accountability, the result is different for each country. Most countries have changed their practices significantly over time.1 Since its creation in 1934, the Bank of Canada has always been mandated “to regulate credit and currency in the best interests of the economic life of the nation.”2

This paper introduces readers to the ongoing independence‑accountability debate. It focuses on the balance that the Bank has struck, and how the trade‑offs that Canada has made about the Bank’s independence and accountability compare with the situations in the UnitedStates and the UnitedKingdom.

2The Cases for Independence andAccountability

2.1The Case for Independence

Central banks can be considered independent if their activities are relatively free from governmentalinfluence.

Central bank independence yields many benefits. When independent central banks make policies, the public can be confident that the government’s political goals have not unduly swayed bank decisions. For example, an independent central bank can prevent a government from lowering interest rates to boost the economy during an election at the expense of long‑termoutput.

There is also evidence that independent central banks help create more stable financial environments. For instance, there is general agreement that central bank independence correlates with stable inflation.3 High independence is also related to fewer and lower government deficits, especially in democraticcountries.4

Common independence practices for modern central banks include, but are not limitedto:

  • allowing the head of the central bank to sit for a predetermined amount of time and putting heavy restrictions on the head’s dismissal;
  • appointing the head of the central bank through a non-political process;
  • giving the central bank, rather than the government, the power to set and/or execute monetarygoals;
  • limiting the government’s ability to borrow money from its centralbank;
  • clearly defining the central bank’s mandate in law;and
  • clearly defining the roles and reporting relationships of central bank officials inlegislation.

2.2The Case for Accountability

Given their far‑reaching powers, central banks can wield a heavy (if indirect) influence on people’s day‑to‑day lives. It is thus unsurprising that people in democratic countries tend to expect a say in their nation’s monetary policy. Central banks are said to be accountable to the extent that they must answer to the government. Countries can strengthen accountability by improving transparency andoversight.

The 2008 financial crisis thrust calls for accountability into headlines around the world. In the following years, public trust in central banks dropped sharply.5 The crisis also sparked many popular movements such as Occupy Wall Street, a grassroots protest opposing major banks’ and large corporations’ influence on economic policy. These movements pointed out a disconnect between ordinary people and decisions about theireconomy.

At the same time, many central banks gained “unconventional” powers in hopes of better managing the crisis.6 These new policies let central banks take stronger actions during emergencies. As a result, central banks today can produce more redistributive results (outcomes that affect some groups more than others) than in thepast. This makes their emergency‑response policies morepolitical.

Even “conventional” monetary policy (day‑to‑day policy aiming to fulfil the central bank’s mandate) can involuntarily favour some groups over others. For instance, there is evidence that lowering inflation may disproportionately increase female unemployment rates.7 By contrast, high inflation may increase the gap between rich andpoor.8 These types of outcomes highlight why governments and the public would want democratic oversight over and transparency for monetarypolicy.

Governments tend to have many tools to hold central banks accountable. Common accountability practices include, but are not limitedto:

  • appointing the head of the central bank through the political process, and allowing for the head’s dismissal if the government is notsatisfied;
  • giving the government, rather than the central bank, the power to set monetary and/or fiscalgoals;
  • clearly defining the central bank’s mandate inlaw;
  • clearly defining the relationship between the government and central bank officials inlegislation;
  • requiring the central bank to publicly and regularly report on its decisions, methodology and finances;and
  • creating standards or codes of conduct for central bankofficials.9

3The Bank of Canada’s Independence–AccountabilityBalance

The Bank of Canada Act sets out the Bank’s mandate, powers and structure. It gives the Bank a considerable level of independence but balances the Bank’s powers with accountabilitymeasures.

Most of this section focuses on the Bank’s structure and powers as set out in law. In practice, there is usually a high level of coordination between the Bank and the government. The two bodies often – but not always – work toward the samegoals.

3.1Bank of Canada Structure

As the Act’s preamble states, the Bank must work “in the best interests of the economic life of the nation.” In other words, the Bank should be answerable to Canadians. It must also work on Canadians’ behalf rather than for a particulargovernment.

The Bank is a Crown corporation; this means the federal government owns the Bank, but the Bank works at arm’s length. The Board of Directors manages the Bank’s day‑to‑day work but does not set monetary policy. The board’s Executive Committee (also known as its Governing Council) sets monetary policy and strategic direction. The Bank hires all other employees internally and regulates them as its own staff rather than as publicservants.

The board is made up of a governor, a senior deputy governor, 12directors and the Deputy Minister of Finance.10 The Minister of Finance appoints each director to the board. Directors sit for renewable, three‑year terms, but the Governor in Council can remove them with cause. Senators, members of Parliament and public servants are not allowed to serve as board members. Board members have one vote each, except the Deputy Minister of Finance, who cannotvote.

One of the board’s most important powers is to appoint the Bank’s governor and deputy governors. However, the Governor in Council11 must approve their choices. The governor and senior deputy governor serve seven‑year terms but may be reappointed at the end of their terms. Although the Governor in Council holds the power to dismiss the governor and senior deputy governor, it needs a valid reason to do so.12 This ensures that the governor and senior deputy governor can work without fear of unjust dismissal, even if the government does not agree with theirdecisions.

The governor, the senior deputy governor, two to four deputy governors, and the Deputy Minister of Finance sit on the Executive Committee. The Executive Committee sets monetary policy by consensus but – as on the Board of Directors – the Deputy Minister of Finance has no vote. The Executive Committee must share its meeting minutes with the board. Although the board may advise the Executive Committee and evaluate its policies, the board cannot overturn the Executive Committee’sdecisions.

Figure 1 – Bank of Canada Accountability Framework

Balancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (1)

Under theAct, the Minister of Finance and the governor must “consult regularly on monetary policy and on its relation to general economic policy.”13 In practice, the two hold weekly meetings. If the Bank and the government disagree on monetary policy, the Minister of Finance may give the governor a written directive that the Bank must follow. This directive must be public, and the government must present the directive to Parliament soon after issuing it. However, to date, no minister has used this directivepower.

Unlike other federal departments and agencies, theBank submits its expenditures to its Board of Directors rather than to the Treasury Board. TheAct also requires annual audits of the Bank’s accounts. The Governor in Council appoints auditors on the Minister of Finance’s recommendation, but the auditors must come from external firms and not from the Office of the Auditor General ofCanada.

3.2Bank of Canada Powers

Overall, theBank has a high level of financial independence, meaning it has control over its budget and finances. This independence ensures that theBank does not depend on government funds to do its work. Instead, theAct provides that the Bank be given a certain amount of capital to cover its operating costs as well as the power to generate income and build up reserve funds. The Bank earns its main source of income by issuing currency at a face value much higher than the cost of producing it. This practice is called “seigniorage.”14

Among the Bank’s most important roles is that of keeping inflation under control. The Bank’s paramount inflation control tool is its power to set the “key interest rate,” more commonly called the “overnight rate.” The overnight rate is the interest rate at which banks may lend short‑term funds to one other. Changing the overnight rate sets in motion a chain of events that affect inflation in the medium and longterm.15 The Bank sets short‑term interest rates independently, but it jointly agrees with the government on long‑term inflation targets through the inflation‑controlagreement.

Under this agreement, theBank agrees to try to keep inflation within a certain range. The initial agreement in1991 has been renewed every fiveyears; its most recent renewal in October2016 set an inflation‑control range of 1% to3%, with a Bank policy target of2%. The aim of the agreement is to give the government and the public confidence that inflation will remain low, stable and predictable, “thus providing a climate that is more favourable to sound, sustained economic growth and jobcreation.”16 It also creates a clear measure of the Bank’s success, for which the governor can easily be held accountable. However, if the Bank misses its target, the agreement does not formally require that it face anyconsequences.

Importantly, theBank is not responsible for the government’s financial stability, as in some other countries. The absence of this responsibility means that theBank is not forced to pay for short‑term government spending at the expense of long‑term stability. However, theBank can lend money to the government at the governor’s discretion. TheBank can provide loans for various reasons, including financing government spending and providing emergencyfunds.17

As an independence measure, theAct limits the terms by which theBank can lend money to the government. Loans cannot exceed one‑third of the Government of Canada’s annual revenue. Although theBank effectively provides loans to the government at near‑zero interest rates,18 the government usually pays near‑market interest rates on itsloans.19

Under theAct, loan repayment times vary; the longest repayment term is 15months or sixmonths for emergency loans. However, theBank has a policy to cap repayment of emergency loans at one day “to prevent the level of government deposits held at theBank from falling below zero.”20 Under the policy,” theBank would also publicly disclose this loan. Having these limits ensures that the government cannot finance all its spending by borrowing endlessly from theBank. Unlimited government borrowing would inevitably lead to higher inflation; the overall demand for goods and services based on the larger amount of money in circulation would grow faster than the economy’s ability toproduce.21

3.3Accountability Through Transparency

Under theAct, theBank is required to publish certain information online to ensure its transparency and, by extension, its accountability. It must post information about its assets and liabilities each week and post its balance sheet each month. It must also send its audited financial statements to the Minister of Finance every year. In addition, Canadians can request the Bank’s records under the Access to InformationAct.

Over the years, the Bank has also introduced voluntary practices to make it more transparent. For example, the Bank announces interest rate decisions on fixed dates, eighttimes per year, to ensure they are predictable. To help Canadians understand them, it also publishes four monetary policy reports and gives four economic progress report speeches each year.22 The speeches give the media an opportunity to ask questions about Bankdecisions.23

The governor and senior deputy governor usually appear many times per year before Senate and House of Commons committees, at the committees’ invitation. This provides Parliament with the chance to ask in‑depth questions about the Bank’sdecisions.

In the recent past, senior Bank officials have given public speeches more frequently and have published them online. TheBank website also publishes its committees’ terms of reference. In addition, governors explain decisions in plain language to make monetary policy more understandable to allCanadians.24 As part of its public outreach, theBank runs a museum in Ottawa that has freeadmission.

4Central Bank Independence and Accountability Abroad

There is no consensus among academics on how best to measure central bank independence and accountability. However, the most commonly used indices in recent studies suggest that Canada requires a high level of accountability from its central bank compared with most countries. They also suggest that theBank has relatively less independence by international standards.25 It is worth noting that these indices measure central bank independence as set out in law, which may transpire differently in practice due to policies or institutionalculture.

In general, the central banks of Organisation for Economic Co‑operation and Development (OECD) countries tend to be highly independent. Many of them are empowered to set their own policies and goals. European central banks tend to be the most independent, which is mainly due to strict limits on governmentborrowing.26

Each country has chosen different trade‑offs for its central bank policies to reflect its preferred balance between independence and accountability. This section highlights these trade‑offs by describing relevant policies for the U.S.Federal Reserve (theFed) and for the U.K.’s Bank of England (BoE). These central banks offer useful comparisons because they both serve economically advanced countries but have different independence and accountabilitypractices.

4.1The United States FederalReserve

The Fed’s level of independence is similar to that of the Bank ofCanada. However, the two banks have very different mandates and structures. The biggest differences are the Fed’s “dual mandate,” its power to set monetary policy and its appointmentprocess.

Most central banks have a single mandate: price stability. Instead, theFed is mandated to control not only price stability – which theFed interprets as low and stable inflation – but also unemployment rates. The Fed generally expects these two to move in opposite directions (e.g., inflation goes up while unemployment rates godown). As a result, the Fed is usually able to control both levers at once. However, price stability and unemployment rates sometimes move up or down together, so theFed may meet one of its goals but not theother.27 In these cases, it can be hard to hold the Fed toaccount.

The Fed has more independence when it comes to setting monetary policy than does theBank. The U.S.Congress sets the Fed’s mandate: “to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long‑term interestrates.”28 However, the Fed is free to interpret its mandate by setting its owntargets.

For most of its history, the Fed had informal targets for inflation but did not reveal formal targets publicly. Beginning in2012, however, it voluntarily published the Statement on Longer‑Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy. This statement set fixed inflation targets at2%. At the same time, the Fed stated it would be “inappropriate” to set fixed employment targets because these assessments are “necessarilyuncertain.”29

The Fed also has distinct appointment processes. The U.S.President appoints seven members of the Board of Governors, plus a board chair and a vice chair. However, theSenate must approve these choices. Board members serve for relatively long terms of 14years, but they cannot be reappointed if they serve a full term. The chair and vice chair – who are also board members – serve relatively short terms of four years. They can nevertheless be reappointed to their respective roles until the expiry of their term as boardmembers.

Twelve different U.S.regions are also represented at theFed, each through Federal Reserve banks. Each reserve bank’s Board of Directors chooses its members. Together, the Board of Governors and fivereserve bank presidents (who serve on a rotating basis) form the Federal Open Market Committee(FOMC). The FOMC sets interest rates eighttimes peryear.

Under the Federal Reserve Act, the U.S.President may remove any appointed member of the Board of Governors, but only “for cause.”30 However, the Federal Reserve Act does not define “cause.” Case law on this subject is also ambiguous. According to legal scholar PeterConti-Brown, “Removability protection does not existfor the Fed Chair, but it exists in unconstitutional form for the reserve bank presidents.”31 Under this interpretation, the U.S.President may hold central bankers to account more easily than is common in other OECDcountries.

4.2The Bank of England

The BoE falls around the global average for central bank independence.32 In some respects, it has a similar mandate and a comparable ability to set policy as theBank. However, there are significant differences. Most importantly, the BoE is highly protected from obligations to lend money to the government. On the other hand, theU.K. imposes more accountability practices on its central bank than Canadadoes.

The BoE has the power to lend money to the U.K. government through an account called the National Loans Fund(NLF). The government can borrow money from the NLF for various reasons, including to finance its spending or pay off debts. However, the U.K.’s National Loans Act1968 puts limits on the government’s ability to borrow from thisfund.33

For example, loans for government projects cannot exceed £95billion and the U.K.Parliament must approve these expenditures. In addition, the government and the BoE must agree on interest rates for money the government holds in the NLF. Similarly, if the government creates securities to pay off debt or ensure financial stability, it can redeem them at the BoE only at market prices (before they mature). These restrictions, among others, ensure that the U.K.government is not able to finance all its spending through the centralbank.

To balance this high level of independence, the U.K.has extensive oversight of the BoE. For instance, the BoE’s Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) – which sets interest rates eighttimes per year – is required under law to publish its MPC minutes. Published decisions must record members’ names and voting preferences. However, the BoE does not need to publish certain minutes if the MPC thinks that information will harm the public interest. In addition, in2014, the BoE also announced it would voluntarily publish full transcripts of monetary policy decisions after eightyears, among other transparencymeasures.

Regarding inflation targeting, the U.K.and Canada have similar practices. Both countries’ central banks are expected to meet inflation targets, but one key difference is that the U.K.government alone sets BoE targets, while in Canada, this decision is made by the Bank of Canada in consultation with the government. Under U.K.law, the Treasury sets objectives for the MPC, which the Chancellor of the Exchequer (who is the equivalent of Canada’s Minister of Finance) publishes each year alongside the budget. The U.K.government also has tools to hold the BoE accountable if inflation moves away from itstarget.

If inflation misses the target by more than one percentage point, the BoE governor must send an open letter to the Chancellor of the Exchequer explaining why this was the case. The letter must also say what the BoE is doing to meet the target, when it expects to meet the target, how its decisions affected – and will continue to affect – economic output, and how its approach aligns with the government’s monetary policy. The BoE must send a new letter in threemonths if inflation is not yet ontarget.

5Trade‑offs at the Bank ofCanada

Comparing central bank policies elsewhere helps highlight the trade‑offs Canada has made when finding a balance between independence and accountability. For instance, by international standards, Canada’s appointment process for Bank officials grants them a fairly high level of independence. Nevertheless, this same process puts more limits on the government’s ability to remove them from office when compared with theU.S.

These countries’ approaches to inflation targeting emphasize similar trade‑offs. The Fed’s ability to set its own inflation targets provides it a high level of independence. By contrast, the U.K.government sets inflation targets and imposes strong oversight mechanisms on the BoE. Since Canada sets its targets through an agreement between the government and theBank, it has found a middle ground between thesetwo.

However, it is sometimes possible to create a high level of accountability while sacrificing very little independence (or vice versa). For example, the requirement that the BoE publish timely minutes of its banking officials’ decisions can help the public to gain insight into how and why policies change. While this transparency lets the public scrutinize its central bank, the BoE does not give up its ability to makedecisions.

In Canada and around the world, the debate around central bank independence and accountability continues. As with any other powerful institution, Canadians should ask themselves if they remain satisfied with the trade‑offs they have made between the Bank’s independence and accountability. This paper provides examples of how practices differ in other countries, but Canadians should decide which elements they value most in their own centralbank.

Notes

†  Library of Parliament Background Papers provide in-depth studies of policy issues. They feature historical background, current information and references, and many anticipate the emergence of the issues they examine. They are prepared by the Parliamentary Information and Research Service, which carries out research for and provides information and analysis to parliamentarians and Senate and House of Commons committees and parliamentary associations in an objective, impartialmanner. [ Return to text ]

  1. See BertrandBlancheton, “Central bank independence in a historical perspective: Myth, lessons and a new model,” Economic Modelling, Vol.52, January2016, pp.101–107.[ Return to text ]
  2. Preamble,” Bank of Canada Act, R.S.C., 1985, c.B‑2.[ Return to text ]
  3. Otmar Issing, “The uncertain future of central bank independence,” Balancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (2)PDF 2.73 MB, 162 pages in Hawks and Doves: Deeds and Words – Economics and Politics of Monetary Policymaking, ed.Sylvester Eijffinger and Donato Masciandaro, Centre for Economic Policy Research Press, London, February2018.[ Return to text ]
  4. Cristina Bodea and Masaaki Higashijima, “Central Bank Independence and Fiscal Policy: Can the Central Bank Restrain Deficit Spending?,” British Journal of Political Science, Vol.47, No.1, January2017.[ Return to text ]
  5. Benjamin Braun, Speaking to the People? Money, Trust, and Central Bank Legitimacy in the Age of Quantitative Easing, Discussion Paper, MaxPlanck Institute for the Study of Societies, Cologne, Germany,2016. [ Return to text ]
  6. Quantitative easing is one unconventional policy adopted widely by central banks since the 2008 financial crisis. With quantitative easing, central banks create money and use it to buy securities. This sets in motion a chain of events intended to reduce interest rates, reduce borrowing costs, encourage lending and stimulate economicactivity. [ Return to text ]
  7. Elissa Braunstein and James Heintz, “Gender bias and central bank policy: employment and inflation reduction,” International Review of Applied Economics, Vol.22, No.2,2008. [ Return to text ]
  8. Andrea Colciago, Anna Samarina and Jakob deHaan, Central bank policies and income and wealth inequality: A surveyBalancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (3)PDF 776 KB, 38 pages, Working Paper no.594, De Nederlandsche Bank, Amsterdam, May2018.[ Return to text ]
  9. See also International Monetary Fund, Code of Good Practices on Transparency in Monetary and Financial Policies: Declaration of PrinciplesBalancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (4)PDF 465 KB, 19 pages, 26September1999.[ Return to text ]
  10. Deputy ministers are unelected officials, appointed by the prime minister, to lead the day‑to‑day operations of theirdepartments.[ Return to text ]
  11. Governor in Council decisions are made by the Governor General on the advice of the federalCabinet.[ Return to text ]
  12. Bank of Canada directors hold office during “good behaviour.” This means that they cannot be dismissed for purely political reasons, but they can be dismissed for violating standards of behaviour and ethics expected of Canadian public officials. See, for example, Bank of Canada, Code of Business Conduct and Ethics for DirectorsBalancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (5)PDF 1.01 MB, 18 pages, August2013.[ Return to text ]
  13. Bank of Canada Act, s.14.1.[ Return to text ]
  14. See Bank of Canada, “Seigniorage,”Balancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (6)PDF 106 KB, 1 page, Backgrounder, March2013. [ Return to text ]
  15. See Bank of Canada, “MonetaryPolicy,”Balancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (7)PDF 1.60 MB, 4pages Backgrounder, April2012.[ Return to text ]
  16. See Bank of Canada, “The Benefits of Low Inflation,”Balancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (8)PDF 124 KB, 1 page Backgrounder, May2013.[ Return to text ]
  17. The Bank of Canada may also provide a defacto loan to the Government of Canada to create money. See Penny Becklumb and Mathieu Frigon, How the Bank of Canada Creates Money for the Federal Government: Operational and Legal Aspects, Publicationno.2015-51-E, Parliamentary Information and Research Service, Library of Parliament, Ottawa, 10August2015.[ Return to text ]
  18. Since the Government of Canada owns the Bank of Canada, theBank must turn over its net revenue from government loans to the government. This has the effect of the Bank lending money to the government at near‑zero interest rates because theBank returns all interest it earns from government loans – minus the Bank’s own expenses – to thegovernment.[ Return to text ]
  19. In most cases (e.g.,loans for an infrastructure project), the Government of Canada uses Bank of Canada loans to pay private businesses or individuals. These businesses or individuals will likely deposit money in private banks, which will in turn deposit the funds at theBank to earn interest. Thus, the Government of Canada pays interest to private banks (through the Bank) at the overnight rate – which is roughly the market rate – minus0.25%.[ Return to text ]
  20. Bank of Canada, Statement of Policy Governing the Acquisition and Management of Financial Assets for the Bank of Canada’s Balance SheetBalancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (9)PDF 175 KB, 10pages, 23November2018, s.7.5.[ Return to text ]
  21. See Bank of Canada, “Monetary Policy – FAQ:4. Why doesn’t the Bank of Canada just print enough money to pay off the nationaldebt?,” Frequently Asked Questions.[ Return to text ]
  22. Another accountability tool central banks can use is “forward guidance.” Central banks provide advance hints to markets about what their next interest rates will be. The Bank of Canada stopped giving routine forward guidance in2014 in an effort to be more transparent about marketuncertainties.[ Return to text ]
  23. See Nicolas Parent, Phoebe Munro and Ron Parker, “An Evaluation of Fixed Announcement Dates,”Balancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (10)PDF 152 KB, 12pages, Bank of Canada Review, Autumn2003, pp.3–11.[ Return to text ]
  24. See Stephen S.Poloz, “Let Me Be Clear: From Transparency to Trust and Understanding,” Address to the Greater Victoria Chamber of Commerce, Victoria, 27June2018.[ Return to text ]
  25. The two most common tools for measuring central bank independence are the Cukierman, Webb and Neyapti(CWN) index and the Grilli, Masciandaro and Tabellini(GMT) index. These methods place different levels of importance on the same factors, sometimes leading to very different results. Unless otherwise stated, this paper uses the most complete and most recent international dataset, coded withCWN: AnaCarolinaGarriga, CBI [central bank independence] Data (database), accessed 25September2018; and AnaCarolinaGarriga, “Central Bank Independence in the World: A New Data Set,” International Interactions, Vol.42, No.5,2016.[ Return to text ]
  26. Garriga, 2016 and2018; and Jakob deHaan etal., “Central Bank Independence Before and After the Crisis,” Comparative Economic Studies, Vol.60, No.2,2018, pp.183–202.[ Return to text ]
  27. Jeffrey M.Lacker and John A.Weinberg, “Inflation and Unemployment: A Layperson’s Guide to the PhillipsCurve”,Balancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (11)PDF 149 KB, 27pages, Economic Quarterly, Vol.93, No.3, Summer2007, pp.201–227.[ Return to text ]
  28. United States, “Section2A: Monetary policy objectives,” Federal Reserve Act.[ Return to text ]
  29. United States Federal Reserve, Statement on Longer‑Run Goals and Monetary Policy StrategyBalancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (12)PDF 651 KB, 1page, 30January2018.[ Return to text ]
  30. United States, “Section10(2): Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,” Federal Reserve Act.[ Return to text ]
  31. PeterConti-Brown, “The Institutions of Federal Reserve Independence,” Yale Journal onRegulation, Vol.32, No.2, Summer2015,p.257.[ Return to text ]
  32. Garriga, CBIData, accessed 25September2018.[ Return to text ]
  33. United Kingdom, National Loans Act1968.[ Return to text ]
Balancing the Independence and Accountability of the Bank of Canada (2024)
Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Nathanael Baumbach

Last Updated:

Views: 5782

Rating: 4.4 / 5 (75 voted)

Reviews: 82% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Nathanael Baumbach

Birthday: 1998-12-02

Address: Apt. 829 751 Glover View, West Orlando, IN 22436

Phone: +901025288581

Job: Internal IT Coordinator

Hobby: Gunsmithing, Motor sports, Flying, Skiing, Hooping, Lego building, Ice skating

Introduction: My name is Nathanael Baumbach, I am a fantastic, nice, victorious, brave, healthy, cute, glorious person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.