Are Economic Forecasts Accurate? | RDP 8302: Economic Forecasts and their Assessment (2024)

I.J. Macfarlane and J.R. Hawkins

August 1983

  • Download the Paper762KB

(a) The issues

The most common criticism of economic forecasts is that they are usually wrong. In a literalsense this is, of course, true; forecasters cannot hope to get things right to the last decimalpoint. In a general sense, however, the proposition is wrong; some economic variables can beforecast to a reasonable degree of accuracy most of the time. To illustrate this point,Table 1 shows recent forecasts of real GDP by the OECD and by the large U.S. forecasting firm,Data Resources Inc (DRI).[2]These were chosen because they are respectively the best-known forecaster of the internationaleconomy and of the U.S. economy.

On the surface, the forecasts are astonishingly accurate. Judged by this sort of performance, itis hard to see why there should be such scepticism about the efficacy of economic forecasting.Unfortunately there is more to the story than appears from Table 1.

Table 1: Forecasts of growth of real GDP

per cent change, year-on-year

OECD forecast of OECD areaDRI forecast of US
Forecast made in previous DecemberOutcomeForecast made in previous SeptemberOutcome
19773–3/43.75.75.3
19783–1/23.74.65.0
19793–1/43.32.82.9
198011.3−0.9−0.4
198111.21.51.9
  • GDP is one of the easier variables to forecast.[3] Even though economistsgive pride of place in their forecasting effort to GDP, and, to a lesser extent, inflation,businesses often have greater need for forecasts of more specific variables. These specificvariables include components of GDP, such as housebuilding, and key prices such as interestrates, exchange rates, commodity prices etc. In these areas the forecasting record isgenerally much poorer.
  • These forecasts are only for one year ahead. It was no doubt useful to know in 1979 that GDPgrowth was going to be negligible in 1980. However, the really important thing to have knownwas that it was going to remain negligible for three years. Forecasters who correctly pickedthe 1980 turning point have been justifiably criticised for failing to see that the worldwas entering the longest recession in the post-war period. It has been established onnumerous occasions (Zarnowitz (1967 and 1979), Christ (1975), Fromm and Klein (1976), McNees(1976), Su (1978)) that, in general, the accuracy of the forecast declines the further aheadis the forecasting period.[4]
  • The period shown in Table 1 is flattering to the forecasts as it did not include a majorshock i.e. an outcome for any one year outside the range of recent experience. It ispossible to find one by going back a few years further. Between 1973 and 1974 GDP growth inthe OECD area fell from 6.1 per cent to 0.9 per cent, by far the sharpest turnaround in thepost war period. In 1974 all the major forecasting groups failed to predict the severity ofthe downturn. (The OECD forecast was 3–1/2 per cent).

This third point is the crucial criticism of economic forecasting. Economic forecasts, at leastof real GDP growth, are usually quite good; they are near the mark in most years and overreasonable periods they outperform simple extrapolative methods. The problem is, that whensomething really large occurs, economic forecasts either fail to pick it or grosslyunderestimate its size.[5]

A better way of illustrating this is to look at some history. Between the first world war andthe Great Depression there was a flourishing economic forecasting industry in the U.S.[6] Its failure topredict the latter event led to its demise. Forecasters that depended for revenue on the sale oftheir forecasts went out of business; others, such as those associated with banks, continued inspite of an equally poor performance.

In the post-war period there have also been a number of major failures by economic forecasters.The main ones were:

  • the false prediction of a recession immediately after World War II;[7]
  • the failure to predict the magnitude of the acceleration in inflation in the earlyseventies;
  • the failure to predict the severity of the fall in output and employment in 1974;
  • over recent years, the failure to predict the duration of the international recession (seeabove), and to predict the rise in interest rates (see below).

In summary, the legitimate criticism of the accuracy of economic forecasts is that they are onlygood at predicting the predictable. When the movements of economic variables are within therange of recently observed movements, forecasting accuracy can seem to be quite good. Whenmovements are outside the range of recent experience, forecasts look poor. All the failures offorecasting listed above, except for the post-World War II recession, are examples of thistendency. It could be claimed that, as most years do not contain an extreme movement in aneconomic variable, economic forecasts are good most of the time. Unfortunately, users ofeconomic forecasts have a disproportionate need to be alerted to the extreme movements.

It is not much comfort to have been correctly told that GDP growth was going to rise from 2–1/2per cent to 3–1/2 per cent, if you were not told that interest rates were going to rise toan all-time record.

(b) Some Australian results

This section looks at an interesting sub-set of Australian forecasts to illustrate some of thepoints made above; for reasons which will be made apparent later, it is not an assessment of therelative worth of different forecasters. The sub-set of forecasts is that collected each Januaryover the last six years by Terry McCrann of The Age. This collection has covered over twentyforecasters in some years, twelve of whom have replied to all five of the completed yearsanalysed in this paper. The calculations in this section are confined to this constant group oftwelve forecasters and the five variables shown in diagram 1, namely, real GDP growth, thechange in the CPI, the level of unemployment, the current account defict and the bond rate. Thetwelve forecasters include private forecasting companies, a university-affiliated economicinstitution, the economic departments of trading banks, other financial institutions and apublic company. The forecasts made by the Treasury and published in Budget Statement No. 2 arenot included in this list as they refer to financial years.[8]

Diagram 1 shows the range of forecasts for each year for each variable, along with theoutcome.[9] It waspossible to compare the outcome with the range of forecasts for the five variables for fiveyears. In these twenty-five observations the outcome was outside the range of forecasts on nineoccasions or 36 per cent of the time. These are shown in Table 2.

Table 2: Occasions on which outcome was outside the range of forecasts
VariableYear
GDP1982
CPI1979
Unemployment1981
1982
Current account1978
1981
Bond rate1979
1980
1981
Are Economic Forecasts Accurate? | RDP 8302: Economic Forecasts and their Assessment (1)
Are Economic Forecasts Accurate? | RDP 8302: Economic Forecasts and their Assessment (2)
Are Economic Forecasts Accurate? | RDP 8302: Economic Forecasts and their Assessment (3)
Are Economic Forecasts Accurate? | RDP 8302: Economic Forecasts and their Assessment (4)
Are Economic Forecasts Accurate? | RDP 8302: Economic Forecasts and their Assessment (5)

This is not a very impressive result, but it is, in a broad sense, consistent with the usualfindings about the effectiveness of forecasting mentioned in the first section.

  • The forecasts perform better than simple extrapolation. To test this proposition,another set of forecast ranges based on simple extrapolation were constructed. Theseeffectively assumed that each variable followed a random process. The forecast ranges foreach year were thus the outcome of the previous year plus or minus the average size ofchanges in the series. When this was calculated, the resulting forecast ranges failed inthirteen occasions out of twenty-five to include the actual outcome. Especially as theranges were about one and a half times as large as those produced by the twelve forecasters,it is reasonable to conclude that they were inferior to the actual forecast ranges. (Anappendix contains details of this extrapolation.)
  • The forecasts are worst for the variable that showed the most extreme movement. Forthree years in a row all forecasters underestimated the bond rate. The bond rate was theonly variable whose movements were outside the range of previous experience; the rise of 6.2percentage points in a three year period was unprecedented. It is true that the number ofunemployed and the dollar value of the current deficit were also at record levels. However,in relative terms, the movements in these variables were not exceptional.
  • Somewhat surprisingly the forecast of the CPI was as good as that for GOP. The reason isthat movements in the CPI were smaller than those for GDP over this period and so abasically extrapolative procedure for forecasting prices worked reasonably well. Thecoefficient of variation of GDP was about 50 per cent against 13 per cent for the CPI. Anearlier draft of this paper covering the first four years' results was able to concludethat the forecasts of GDP were better than for the other variables considered, however therecession in 1982 altered that conclusion.[10]In short, GDP and unemployment experienced a very large shock within the evaluation periodwhile prices did npt.

This five-year period was chosen as it was used by Caton (1982) to show DRI resultswhich he said “should sustain (him) at least through (his) next two bouts ofscepticism of all forecasting methods”. The OECD results were from the Decemberissues of the “Economic Outlook”.[2]

Real GDP is generally forecast better than the other major macro-economicvariable – the inflation rate. The coefficient of variation of OECD forecasts forinflation is about 1–1/2 times larger than for GDP. Caton (1982) says of the DRIinflation forecasts over 1977 to 1981 that they are “uninspired, marginallyoutperforming the naive model, which they closely resemble”. Zarnowitz (1979) andDaub (1981) also found that inflation forecasts were hardly distinguishable fromextrapolations.[3]

One neglected reason for this is that forecasters become excessively cautious when theyextend the forecasting period. They are often prepared to forecast extreme outcomes(i.e. large rises or falls in economic variables) in the near future, but are reluctantto do so further ahead. Most quarterly or half yearly forecasts incorporate “areturn to normality” after about six months or a year (this can be verified forOECD half yearly forecasts). This is because extreme forecasts are hard to defend. Inthe case of forecasts made for only six months or a year ahead, it is often possible todefend them by reference to current conditions, leading indicators, anticipations dataetc. Forecasts out beyond a year cannot rely on such information for their defence.[4]

The first of tnese points – that economic forecasts are better than simpleextrapolation – has been made by Zarnowitz (1967, 1978), Mincer and Zarnowitz(1969), Christ (1975) and Shapiro and Garman (1981). The second point, namely thatforecasts are worst when large changes are occurring, has been documented by Zarnowitz(1979) and Shapiro and Garman (1981).[5]

By 1927 there were more than half a dozen commercial forecasting services with anational clientele. The academic world was also represented e.g. by the Harvard EconomicService and Irving Fisher who published an annual forecast in the American EconomicReview. Systematic assessments of forecasting accuracy were also carried out. Some ofthese are described in Shapiro and Garman (1981).[6]

See Sapir (1949) and Zarnowitz (1978).[7]

Pagan et. al (September 1982) point out that many private forecasters “seem toadjustment (their forecasts) towards those given in the Budget”. This wouldsuggest that the Treasury forecast would end up in the middle of the range of forecastsby January, even if it had not been moved. As all calculations in this section are basedon ranges of forecasts, the omission of the Treasury forecast would not be likely tolead to major changes in the conclusions.[8]

The outcomes used throughout this paper are the latest estimate available rather thanthe first estimate. Although it is possible to argue for either, the prevailing view isthat “the main object of forecasting is to anticipate what will actually happen inthe economy rather than what the data source agencies, on the basis of incompleteinformation, initially estimated had happened”. McNees (1981b). Others have takena different view. Suprisingly it makes little difference which estimate of the outcomeis used for comparison. In fact some studies have found that forecasts have been closerto the final outcomes than to the preliminary ones.[9]

Note that the specification of some of the forecast variables made it easier for theforecasters in 1982 than recent events might suggest. For example:

  • Unemployment had to be forecast for mid-year but the big shakeout did notoccur until the second half of the year. Although the June outcome was slightlyabove the top of the forecast range, the end-year outcome was well above it;
  • The bond rate had to be forecast for the end of the year. By mid-year ithad risen to an all-time high which was well above the top of the forecastrange. It was not until December that the bond rate fell back into the forecastrange.

[10]

Are Economic Forecasts Accurate? | RDP 8302: Economic Forecasts and their Assessment (2024)
Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Horacio Brakus JD

Last Updated:

Views: 5898

Rating: 4 / 5 (71 voted)

Reviews: 94% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Horacio Brakus JD

Birthday: 1999-08-21

Address: Apt. 524 43384 Minnie Prairie, South Edda, MA 62804

Phone: +5931039998219

Job: Sales Strategist

Hobby: Sculling, Kitesurfing, Orienteering, Painting, Computer programming, Creative writing, Scuba diving

Introduction: My name is Horacio Brakus JD, I am a lively, splendid, jolly, vivacious, vast, cheerful, agreeable person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.